- Sign In
- Tutor Bios
-
Test Prep
GRADUATE SCHOOL
Search 50+ Tests
Loading Page
-
Academic Tutoring
elementary tutoring
Search 350+ Subjects
Loading Page
- About
Create an account to track your scores
and create your own practice tests:
All New SAT Reading Resources
The passage is adapted from Ngonghala CN, et. al’s “Poverty, Disease, and the Ecology of Complex Systems” © 2014 Ngonghala et al.
In his landmark treatise, An Essay on the Principle of Population, Reverend Thomas Robert Malthus argued that population growth will necessarily exceed the growth rate of the means of subsistence, making poverty inevitable. The system of feedbacks that Malthus posited creates a situation similar to what social scientists now term a “poverty trap”: i.e., a self-reinforcing mechanism that causes poverty to persist. Malthus’s erroneous assumptions, which did not account for rapid technological progress, rendered his core prediction wrong: the world has enjoyed unprecedented economic development in theensuing two centuries due to technology-driven productivity growth.
Nonetheless, for the billion people who still languish in chronic extreme poverty, Malthus’s ideas about the importance of biophysical and biosocial feedback (e.g., interactions between human behavior and resource availability) to the dynamics of economic systems still ring true. Indeed, while they were based on observations of human populations, Malthus's ideas had reverberations throughout the life sciences. His insights were based on important underlying processes that provided inspiration to both Darwin and Wallace as they independently derived the theory of evolution by natural selection. Likewise, these principles underlie standard models of population biology, including logistic population growth models, predator-prey models, and the epidemiology of host-pathogen dynamics.
The economics literature on poverty traps, where extreme poverty of some populations persists alongside economic prosperity among others, has a history in various schools of thought. The most Malthusian of models were advanced later by Leibenstein and Nelson, who argued that interactions between economic, capital, and population growth can create a subsistence-level equilibrium. Today, the most common models of poverty traps are rooted in neoclassical growth theory, which is the dominant foundational framework for modeling economic growth. Though sometimes controversial, poverty trap concepts have been integral to some of the most sweeping efforts to catalyze economic development, such as those manifest in the Millennium Development Goals.
The modern economics literature on poverty traps, however, is strikingly silent about the role of feedbacks from biophysical and biosocial processes. Two overwhelming characteristics of under-developed economies and the poorest, mostly rural, subpopulations in those countries are (i) the dominant role of resource-dependent primary production—from soils, fisheries, forests, and wildlife—as the root source of income and (ii) the high rates of morbidity and mortality due to parasitic and infectious diseases. For basic subsistence, the extremely poor rely on human capital that is directly generated from their ability to obtain resources, and thus critically influenced by climate and soil that determine the success of food production. These resources in turn influence the nutrition and health of individuals, but can also be influenced by a variety of other biophysical processes. For example, infectious and parasitic diseases effectively steal human resources for their own survival and transmission. Yet scientists rarely integrate even the most rudimentary frameworks for understanding these ecological processes into models of economic growth and poverty.
This gap in the literature represents a major missed opportunity to advance our understanding of coupled ecological-economic systems. Through feedbacks between lower-level localized behavior and the higher-level processes that they drive, ecological systems are known to demonstrate complex emergent properties that can be sensitive to initial conditions. A large range of ecological systems—as revealed in processes like desertification, soil degradation, coral reef bleaching, and epidemic disease—have been characterized by multiple stable states, with direct consequences for the livelihoods of the poor. These multiple stable states, which arise from nonlinear positive feedbacks, imply sensitivity to initial conditions.
While Malthus’s original arguments about the relationship between population growth and resource availability were overly simplistic (resulting in only one stable state of subsistence poverty), they led to more sophisticated characterizations of complex ecological processes. In this light, we suggest that breakthroughs in understanding poverty can still benefit from two of his enduring contributions to science: (i) models that are true to underlying mechanisms can lead to critical insights, particularly of complex emergent properties, that are not possible from pure phenomenological models; and (ii) there are significant implications for models that connect human economic behavior to biological constraints.
World Population, 1990-2015
YEAR |
NUMBER OF PEOPLE (in billions) |
1990 |
5.3 |
1993 |
5.5 |
1996 |
5.8 |
1999 |
6.1 |
2002 |
6.3 |
2005 |
6.4 |
2008 |
6.6 |
2010 |
6.8 |
2015 |
7.3 |
The above table plots the world population, in billions of people, from 1990 through 2015
Percent of Population Living in Extreme Poverty
1990 |
1993 |
1996 |
1999 |
2002 |
2005 |
2008 |
2010 |
2015 |
|
Europe and Central Asia |
2 |
3 |
4 |
4 |
2 |
2 |
1 |
3 |
1 |
Middle East |
8 |
6 |
5 |
5 |
5 |
5 |
5 |
6 |
5 |
Latin American and Caribbean |
11 |
10 |
10 |
12 |
14 |
9 |
5 |
5 |
4 |
East Asia and Pacific |
55 |
52 |
37 |
37 |
30 |
18 |
16 |
13 |
8 |
South Asia |
53 |
53 |
49 |
45 |
45 |
38 |
36 |
32 |
22 |
Sub-Saharan African |
57 |
60 |
48 |
59 |
57 |
51 |
48 |
47 |
42 |
The table above shows the percentage of people in each region that lived in extreme poverty, as defined by the World Bank, for each of the years plotted. The seventh region, North America, is not shown, as its extreme poverty rate fell below the minimum rate for tracking in this study.
Which of the following conclusions is best supported by the two tables?
In 1999, there were more people living in extreme poverty in South Asia than in East Asia and the Pacific.
As of 2015, less than 3.5 billion people in the world lived in extreme poverty.
Fewer people in Latin America & the Caribbean lived in poverty in 2008 than in 2002.
Extreme poverty is not a major concern in Europe & Central Asia.
Which of the following conclusions is best supported by the two tables?
In 1999, there were more people living in extreme poverty in South Asia than in East Asia and the Pacific.
Fewer people in Latin America & the Caribbean lived in poverty in 2008 than in 2002.
Extreme poverty is not a major concern in Europe & Central Asia.
As of 2015, less than 3.5 billion people in the world lived in extreme poverty.
To answer this question, we need to compare the answer options to the two tables. When you are looking at the answer options, keep in mind that the correct answer must be supported by both tables, not just one. Let’s start with “in 1999, there were more people living in extreme poverty in South Asia than in East Asia and the Pacific”. Note that the table that compares regions only deals with percents (percentage of people in that region living in poverty) but not with actual numbers of people. Without an idea of how many people live in each region, we can’t compare total numbers. Next, “fewer people in Latin America & the Caribbean lived in poverty in 2008 than in 2002” has the same problem - without knowing how many people are in each region, we can’t draw conclusions about the total number of people (for example, if one region has one billion people and another has one hundred, you could take the same percentage of each region and get wildly different actual numbers). Answer choice “extreme poverty is not a major concern in Europe & Central Asia” is interesting in that it offers a value judgment - from the numbers you might think “only 1% of people in this region live in extreme poverty, and 1% isn’t a big number” but ask yourself: if it’s 1% of 500 million people, isn’t it possibly a major concern to those 5 million people? Value judgments like this are very hard to prove, and when you’re asked to draw a conclusion on the SAT you need to be able to prove your answer. This leaves us with, “as of 2015, less than 3.5 billion people in the world lived in extreme poverty”. Without even having to go back and reference the tables you should notice that this choice mentions a population size- which is discussed in the first table- and poverty level- which is covered in the second table. To double check, we can look at the first table and see that is 2015 there are 7.3 billion people in the world- which makes 3.5 billion people about half of the population. Looking at the second table in 2015 we can see that all poverty rates are substantially below 50%, so we can draw this conclusion.
The passage is adapted from Ngonghala CN, et. al’s “Poverty, Disease, and the Ecology of Complex Systems” © 2014 Ngonghala et al.
In his landmark treatise, An Essay on the Principle of Population, Reverend Thomas Robert Malthus argued that population growth will necessarily exceed the growth rate of the means of subsistence, making poverty inevitable. The system of feedbacks that Malthus posited creates a situation similar to what social scientists now term a “poverty trap”: i.e., a self-reinforcing mechanism that causes poverty to persist. Malthus’s erroneous assumptions, which did not account for rapid technological progress, rendered his core prediction wrong: the world has enjoyed unprecedented economic development in theensuing two centuries due to technology-driven productivity growth.
Nonetheless, for the billion people who still languish in chronic extreme poverty, Malthus’s ideas about the importance of biophysical and biosocial feedback (e.g., interactions between human behavior and resource availability) to the dynamics of economic systems still ring true. Indeed, while they were based on observations of human populations, Malthus's ideas had reverberations throughout the life sciences. His insights were based on important underlying processes that provided inspiration to both Darwin and Wallace as they independently derived the theory of evolution by natural selection. Likewise, these principles underlie standard models of population biology, including logistic population growth models, predator-prey models, and the epidemiology of host-pathogen dynamics.
The economics literature on poverty traps, where extreme poverty of some populations persists alongside economic prosperity among others, has a history in various schools of thought. The most Malthusian of models were advanced later by Leibenstein and Nelson, who argued that interactions between economic, capital, and population growth can create a subsistence-level equilibrium. Today, the most common models of poverty traps are rooted in neoclassical growth theory, which is the dominant foundational framework for modeling economic growth. Though sometimes controversial, poverty trap concepts have been integral to some of the most sweeping efforts to catalyze economic development, such as those manifest in the Millennium Development Goals.
The modern economics literature on poverty traps, however, is strikingly silent about the role of feedbacks from biophysical and biosocial processes. Two overwhelming characteristics of under-developed economies and the poorest, mostly rural, subpopulations in those countries are (i) the dominant role of resource-dependent primary production—from soils, fisheries, forests, and wildlife—as the root source of income and (ii) the high rates of morbidity and mortality due to parasitic and infectious diseases. For basic subsistence, the extremely poor rely on human capital that is directly generated from their ability to obtain resources, and thus critically influenced by climate and soil that determine the success of food production. These resources in turn influence the nutrition and health of individuals, but can also be influenced by a variety of other biophysical processes. For example, infectious and parasitic diseases effectively steal human resources for their own survival and transmission. Yet scientists rarely integrate even the most rudimentary frameworks for understanding these ecological processes into models of economic growth and poverty.
This gap in the literature represents a major missed opportunity to advance our understanding of coupled ecological-economic systems. Through feedbacks between lower-level localized behavior and the higher-level processes that they drive, ecological systems are known to demonstrate complex emergent properties that can be sensitive to initial conditions. A large range of ecological systems—as revealed in processes like desertification, soil degradation, coral reef bleaching, and epidemic disease—have been characterized by multiple stable states, with direct consequences for the livelihoods of the poor. These multiple stable states, which arise from nonlinear positive feedbacks, imply sensitivity to initial conditions.
While Malthus’s original arguments about the relationship between population growth and resource availability were overly simplistic (resulting in only one stable state of subsistence poverty), they led to more sophisticated characterizations of complex ecological processes. In this light, we suggest that breakthroughs in understanding poverty can still benefit from two of his enduring contributions to science: (i) models that are true to underlying mechanisms can lead to critical insights, particularly of complex emergent properties, that are not possible from pure phenomenological models; and (ii) there are significant implications for models that connect human economic behavior to biological constraints.
World Population, 1990-2015
YEAR |
NUMBER OF PEOPLE (in billions) |
1990 |
5.3 |
1993 |
5.5 |
1996 |
5.8 |
1999 |
6.1 |
2002 |
6.3 |
2005 |
6.4 |
2008 |
6.6 |
2010 |
6.8 |
2015 |
7.3 |
The above table plots the world population, in billions of people, from 1990 through 2015
Percent of Population Living in Extreme Poverty
1990 |
1993 |
1996 |
1999 |
2002 |
2005 |
2008 |
2010 |
2015 |
|
Europe and Central Asia |
2 |
3 |
4 |
4 |
2 |
2 |
1 |
3 |
1 |
Middle East |
8 |
6 |
5 |
5 |
5 |
5 |
5 |
6 |
5 |
Latin American and Caribbean |
11 |
10 |
10 |
12 |
14 |
9 |
5 |
5 |
4 |
East Asia and Pacific |
55 |
52 |
37 |
37 |
30 |
18 |
16 |
13 |
8 |
South Asia |
53 |
53 |
49 |
45 |
45 |
38 |
36 |
32 |
22 |
Sub-Saharan African |
57 |
60 |
48 |
59 |
57 |
51 |
48 |
47 |
42 |
The table above shows the percentage of people in each region that lived in extreme poverty, as defined by the World Bank, for each of the years plotted. The seventh region, North America, is not shown, as its extreme poverty rate fell below the minimum rate for tracking in this study.
Which of the following best describes how the data in the two tables supports Malthus’s prediction that population growth will necessarily exceed the growth rate of the means of subsistence, making poverty an inevitable consequence?
It contradicts Malthus’s prediction, because it shows that poverty is decreasing even while the population is increasing.
It contradicts Malthus’s prediction, because it demonstrates that poverty remains highest in the same regions of the world year after year.
It supports Malthus’s prediction, because it shows that poverty is still a major problem in the world.
It supports Malthus’s prediction, because it demonstrates that poverty is a problem that can be solved in certain regions.
Which of the following best describes how the data in the two tables supports Malthus’s prediction that population growth will necessarily exceed the growth rate of the means of subsistence, making poverty an inevitable consequence?
It contradicts Malthus’s prediction, because it demonstrates that poverty remains highest in the same regions of the world year after year.
It supports Malthus’s prediction, because it shows that poverty is still a major problem in the world.
It supports Malthus’s prediction, because it demonstrates that poverty is a problem that can be solved in certain regions.
It contradicts Malthus’s prediction, because it shows that poverty is decreasing even while the population is increasing.
If we look at the first table, we can see that from 1990 to 2015 the world population did grow, which does support part of Malthus’s prediction. However, if we look at the second table, we see that from 1990-2015 the percentage of people living poverty actually decreases across each world region (and dramatically so in those regions that were >50% in 1990). Thus, as population increased, poverty decreased. This contradicts Mathus’s prediction overall so we can eliminate answer choices that claim to support his prediction: “ it supports Malthus’s prediction, because it shows that poverty is still a major problem in the world “ and “it supports Malthus’s prediction, because it demonstrates that poverty is a problem that can be solved in certain regions”.
Looking at the remaining options, “it contradicts Malthus’s prediction, because it demonstrates that poverty remains highest in the same regions of the world year after year” is a true statement based on the second table; however, this has nothing to do with Mathus’s prediction so we can eliminate it. This leaves us with, “it contradicts Malthus’s prediction, because it shows that poverty is decreasing even while the population is increasing” as the correct answer. This statement is supported by both of the tables and does contradict Malthus’s overall prediction because that tables show that as population increased, poverty decreased.
Report an issue with this question
If you've found an issue with this question, please let us know. With the help of the community we can continue to improve our educational resources.
DMCA Complaint
If you believe that content available by means of the Website (as defined in our Terms of Service) infringes one or more of your copyrights, please notify us by providing a written notice (“Infringement Notice”) containing the information described below to the designated agent listed below. If Varsity Tutors takes action in response to an Infringement Notice, it will make a good faith attempt to contact the party that made such content available by means of the most recent email address, if any, provided by such party to Varsity Tutors.
Your Infringement Notice may be forwarded to the party that made the content available or to third parties such as ChillingEffects.org.
Please be advised that you will be liable for damages (including costs and attorneys’ fees) if you materially misrepresent that a product or activity is infringing your copyrights. Thus, if you are not sure content located on or linked-to by the Website infringes your copyright, you should consider first contacting an attorney.
Please follow these steps to file a notice:
You must include the following:
A physical or electronic signature of the copyright owner or a person authorized to act on their behalf; An identification of the copyright claimed to have been infringed; A description of the nature and exact location of the content that you claim to infringe your copyright, in \ sufficient detail to permit Varsity Tutors to find and positively identify that content; for example we require a link to the specific question (not just the name of the question) that contains the content and a description of which specific portion of the question – an image, a link, the text, etc – your complaint refers to; Your name, address, telephone number and email address; and A statement by you: (a) that you believe in good faith that the use of the content that you claim to infringe your copyright is not authorized by law, or by the copyright owner or such owner’s agent; (b) that all of the information contained in your Infringement Notice is accurate, and (c) under penalty of perjury, that you are either the copyright owner or a person authorized to act on their behalf.
Send your complaint to our designated agent at:
Charles Cohn
Varsity Tutors LLC
101 S. Hanley Rd, Suite 300
St. Louis, MO 63105
Or fill out the form below: